The Relationship Between Inflation and Unemployment: Exploring the Phillips Curve

Posted on May 14, 2025 by Rodrigo Ricardo

Understanding the Phillips Curve Theory

The relationship between inflation and unemployment has been one of the most studied topics in macroeconomics since economist A.W. Phillips first identified an inverse correlation between wage growth and unemployment in Britain in 1958. This observation evolved into the Phillips Curve, which posits a short-term trade-off between inflation and unemployment—when unemployment is low, inflation tends to be high, and vice versa. The theoretical foundation suggests that as unemployment falls and labor markets tighten, workers gain bargaining power to demand higher wages, which businesses then pass on to consumers as higher prices, creating inflationary pressure. Conversely, high unemployment weakens workers’ bargaining position, leading to slower wage growth and reduced inflation. This relationship became a cornerstone of Keynesian economic policy in the mid-20th century, with policymakers believing they could “choose” their preferred combination of inflation and unemployment through demand management policies. Governments often exploited this perceived trade-off, stimulating economies to reduce unemployment while accepting somewhat higher inflation as the necessary cost.

However, the original Phillips Curve relationship began breaking down in the 1970s with the emergence of stagflation—the simultaneous occurrence of high inflation and high unemployment—which contradicted the basic model. Economists Milton Friedman and Edmund Phelps revolutionized the understanding by introducing the concept of the natural rate of unemployment (later called the Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment or NAIRU) and expectations-augmented Phillips Curve. Their work showed that the trade-off only exists in the short run when inflation expectations remain stable, while in the long run, there is no permanent trade-off as expectations adjust. When workers and firms anticipate higher inflation, they build it into wage and price setting behavior, meaning that any unemployment reduction below the natural rate would only cause accelerating inflation rather than a stable higher rate. This insight fundamentally changed macroeconomic policy, emphasizing that attempts to push unemployment permanently below its natural rate through expansionary policies would only lead to ever-increasing inflation without lasting employment gains. The expectations-augmented Phillips Curve remains a crucial framework for central banks today as they balance inflation and employment objectives.

Empirical Evidence and Modern Adaptations of the Phillips Curve

Over recent decades, economists have observed that the Phillips Curve relationship appears to have flattened in many advanced economies, meaning that changes in unemployment now correspond with smaller movements in inflation than in previous periods. This flattening has several potential explanations, including globalization reducing domestic wage pressures, weaker worker bargaining power due to declining unionization, and better-anchored inflation expectations due to credible central bank policies. Some research suggests the curve may have become non-linear—steeper when unemployment is very low but flatter at moderate unemployment levels—helping explain why inflation remained subdued in many countries despite falling unemployment in the 2010s, only to surge when labor markets became extremely tight post-pandemic. The changing nature of labor markets with more gig work and flexible arrangements may have also altered traditional wage-price dynamics. Additionally, the increasing importance of global supply chains means domestic unemployment conditions now compete with international cost pressures in determining inflation outcomes.

Modern versions of the Phillips Curve incorporate additional variables beyond unemployment that influence inflation dynamics. These include measures of labor market slack beyond the headline unemployment rate (such as prime-age employment-to-population ratios or underemployment measures), inflation expectations (both survey-based and market-derived), supply shock variables (like commodity prices or supply chain indicators), and even behavioral factors. Some models distinguish between goods inflation (more sensitive to global factors and supply conditions) and services inflation (more tied to domestic labor costs). The New Keynesian Phillips Curve, widely used in central bank models, emphasizes forward-looking expectations and price rigidities—the idea that firms don’t continuously adjust prices due to menu costs and other frictions. These sophisticated models attempt to capture the complex reality that simple unemployment-inflation trade-offs have become less reliable predictors, though the fundamental insight that tight labor markets eventually create inflationary pressures remains valid. The challenge for policymakers lies in determining which version of the Phillips Curve best applies to current conditions when making decisions about interest rates and other tools.

Policy Implications and the Dual Mandate Challenge

The evolving understanding of the inflation-unemployment relationship has significant implications for central banks like the Federal Reserve that operate under dual mandates to maintain both price stability and maximum employment. In periods where the Phillips Curve appears flat, policymakers face difficult judgments about how much labor market tightening they can tolerate before inflation emerges. Waiting too long to respond risks allowing inflation to become entrenched, requiring more painful policy tightening later, while acting too preemptively could needlessly sacrifice employment gains. The post-2021 inflation surge demonstrated these challenges vividly—many central banks initially viewed rising prices as transitory partly because unemployment remained elevated, only to recognize later that pandemic had fundamentally altered labor market dynamics and the inflation process. This experience has led to renewed debate about whether policymakers had become over-reliant on Phillips Curve frameworks that no longer captured modern economic realities, particularly the growing importance of supply-side factors.

The concept of the natural rate of unemployment (NAIRU) presents particular difficulties for policy implementation because it is unobservable and can change over time due to demographic shifts, technological changes, and labor market policies. Estimates of NAIRU have proven unreliable in real-time, making it hard for policymakers to know when unemployment has fallen below sustainable levels. Some economists argue that an overemphasis on NAIRU risks keeping unemployment unnecessarily high, particularly if structural changes have permanently lowered the natural rate. Alternative approaches suggest focusing more directly on inflation expectations and actual inflation outcomes rather than theoretical unemployment thresholds. The policy dilemma intensifies in recessions, when stimulating demand to reduce unemployment may conflict with inflation targets, or during supply shocks when inflation rises despite weak labor markets. These situations require careful balancing of the dual mandate objectives, recognizing that the short-run trade-offs may differ substantially from historical patterns and that policy impacts occur with uncertain lags.

International Comparisons and Institutional Factors

Cross-country comparisons reveal significant variations in how the inflation-unemployment relationship manifests, influenced by differing labor market institutions and policy frameworks. Countries with more centralized wage bargaining systems (like some Nordic nations) often exhibit different Phillips Curve dynamics than those with decentralized systems (like the U.S.), as coordinated wage setting can sometimes prevent inflationary spirals even at low unemployment. Nations with stronger automatic stabilizers and active labor market policies may experience less volatility in the relationship, as these mechanisms help smooth transitions during economic fluctuations. The degree of labor market flexibility also matters—economies with strict employment protection laws might see slower wage adjustment to changing conditions, potentially altering the traditional Phillips Curve patterns. Additionally, countries with histories of high inflation often see faster passthrough from labor costs to prices as firms and workers build inflation expectations into their decisions more quickly.

The European experience provides particularly interesting contrasts with the United States. Many European countries maintained higher unemployment rates than the U.S. for decades while often having lower inflation, challenging simple Phillips Curve interpretations. This “Eurosclerosis” period suggested structural factors could dominate cyclical relationships. Japan’s experience with very low unemployment and minimal inflation for years also pushed economists to reconsider standard models. Emerging markets frequently show different patterns, where currency fluctuations and imported inflation often overshadow domestic labor market conditions in determining price levels. These international differences highlight that while the Phillips Curve provides a valuable conceptual framework, its specific form and policy implications depend heavily on institutional contexts that vary across time and place. This complexity argues against one-size-fits-all policy approaches and emphasizes the need for country-specific analysis when applying these concepts.

Future Directions and Alternative Frameworks

As traditional Phillips Curve relationships have become less predictable, economists have explored alternative frameworks to understand the inflation-unemployment nexus. Some research focuses on the role of labor market concentration—with fewer employers in many local labor markets, firms may have more power to suppress wages even at low unemployment, potentially breaking the traditional wage-price spiral. Other work examines how demographic changes, like aging populations, affect the relationship by altering labor force participation dynamics. The growing “gig economy” and non-traditional work arrangements may also modify how tight labor markets translate into wage and price pressures. Some economists propose moving beyond unemployment-based measures to broader indicators of labor market health that might better predict inflation, including job vacancy rates, quit rates, and hours worked. The COVID-19 pandemic’s impact on labor supply has further complicated these analyses, suggesting health concerns and care responsibilities can create labor market tightness independent of traditional demand factors.

At the frontier of research, machine learning techniques are being applied to uncover complex, non-linear relationships in labor market and inflation data that traditional econometric models might miss. Other innovative approaches examine sectoral Phillips Curves—recognizing that different industries may have distinct inflation-unemployment relationships that aggregate into overall patterns. The increasing availability of real-time data from job platforms and price scanners offers potential to develop more responsive indicators. These developments don’t invalidate the core Phillips Curve insight that resource utilization affects price stability, but they do suggest that 21st century economies require more sophisticated models than the original formulation. For policymakers, this evolving understanding means maintaining flexibility in their frameworks while staying anchored to fundamental principles—that sustainably achieving both price stability and maximum employment requires understanding how labor market conditions interact with inflation expectations and price-setting behavior in an increasingly complex global economy.

Author

Rodrigo Ricardo

A writer passionate about sharing knowledge and helping others learn something new every day.

No hashtags